19 January 2021

We need to direct ends, not means

John Kay, reviewing Mission Economy, discusses the author, Mariana Mazzucato's, contention that 'we need a “solutions based economy”, driven and co-ordinated by more powerful governments engaged in every stage of the process of innovation' in order to solve urgent global problems as effectively as the Apollo space programme achieved its goal of landing men on the moon and returning them to Earth. But, Mr Kay writes:

Apollo was a success because the objective was specific and limited; the basic science was well understood, even if many subsidiary technological developments were needed to make the mission feasible; and the political commitment to the project was sufficiently strong to make budget overruns almost irrelevant. Centrally directed missions have sometimes succeeded when these conditions are in place; Apollo was a response to the Soviet Union’s pioneering launch of a human into space, and the greatest achievement of the USSR was the mobilisation of resources to defeat Nazi Germany. Nixon’s war on cancer, explicitly modelled on the Apollo programme, was a failure because cancer is not a single illness and too little was then — or now — understood about the science of cell mutation. Mao’s Great Leap Forward, a vain bid to create an industrial society within five years, proved to be one of the greatest economic and humanitarian disasters in human history. At least 30m people died.

With political direction of innovation we regularly encounter grandiosity of ambition and scale; the belief that strength of commitment overcomes practical problems; an absence of honest feedback; the suppression of sceptical comment and marginalisation of sceptical commentators. Mission Economy by Mariana Mazzucato — could moonshot thinking help fix the planet?, John Kay, 15 January (emphasis added)
I agree: political direction of innovation doesn't work. But political direction of the outcome, I believe, can work, if the necessary innovation is contracted out to motivated bodies, be they in the public or private sector. Governments are good at specifying goals, and democratic governments are good at specifying society's goals. They are also efficient at raising the revenue necessary for their achievement. Where they are not so effective is in dictating how that revenue shall be spent and who will do the spending. As Mr Kay continues: 

All these were seen in Britain’s experience with Concorde, the Channel Tunnel and the AGR nuclear reactor programme, some of the worst commercial projects in history. More recently, there is the £12bn wasted on the NHS computerisation programme ....

This is why I continue to advocate the Social Policy Bonds concept, which allows governments to do what they are best at: specifying a desirable outcomes, while letting motivated bodies compete for the right to join a protean coalition that will co-operate, continuously, until the outcome has been achieved. In that way, goals can be long term in nature - see my piece on global goals, for example. The composition and structure of that coalition can and, most likely, will change, but at every point in time, its attributes will be subordinated to the over-arching goals specified by government, in consultation with the public. Whoever issues Social Policy Bonds - and it needn't be government - cannot specify the diverse, adaptive policies that will be necessary to solve our most urgent, big, complex problems. But they can specify the outcome, and in so doing ensure that the most efficient problem solvers are rewarded in ways that directly correlate with their contribution.

No comments: