This is a short, updated, and so far unpublished, piece on applying the Social Policy Bond principle to conflict in the Middle East
Peace in the Middle East: giving self-interest a chance
I have no solution to the anxieties and potential
catastrophes facing Israel, nor to the wider problems facing the citizens of
all the Middle Eastern countries. What I offer instead is a means to encourage
people to find solutions. Everybody has their own ideas about what should be
done. I offer a way of channelling resources into those ideas - but only if
they are effective and efficient.
Incentives
Where we are now: rockets are daily fired into Israel; we
might well be on the brink of a nuclear calamity; and the entire region is a
seething cauldron of every sort of hatred: ethnic, confessional, sectarian and
gender.
Most ordinary people in the region, given time to reflect
and the freedom to express their opinions would like nothing more than to see
an end to the violence in the region. But there are too many people with a
vested interest in keeping conflict going. They include the men of religion,
the ideologues, and many of the politicians and bureaucrats. The international
agencies and the military, whatever their intentions, aren’t exactly helping
either. There are also, of course, the more nakedly financial incentives on the
‘defence’ industries and their beneficiaries in government, to fuel the fear of
conflict. Well-meaning idealists on all sides do what they can, but their
efforts are relentlessly undermined by the powerful people and institutions
that want them to fail.
Peace above all
Perhaps it’s now to time to give people incentives to create
and sustain peace, rather than conflict.
For my proposal to work we need a verifiable definition of peace, which
will probably consist of an array of conditions that have to be satisfied and
sustained. These could include:
·
a much-reduced number of people killed in
conflict;
·
a much-reduced level of terrorist events, or
military incursions;
·
no use of nuclear weapons.
Under my proposal, investors in the bonds would be rewarded
once these, and other agreed conditions had been satisfied and sustained for,
say, 30 years.
We need to be just as single-minded as the arms merchants
and fanatics in wanting peace to the exclusion of everything, which might mean putting aside feelings of fairness,
justice and history, except insofar as they help our cause. Being single-minded
about our goal doesn’t mean that we simply pick the one project that we think
will work and go for that. The circumstances that fan the flames of conflict
vary radically from place to place and over time. No one solution, nor even an
array of solutions will work all the time. We need a system that will encourage
those projects that are most efficient for their time and place, and that will terminate
projects when they become inefficient. In short, we need diverse, adaptive
solutions.
And we need a way of promoting peace that can modify or circumvent
people's uncooperative or obstructive behaviour. We need to mobilise the
interests of the far greater number of people who want peace. We need to find a
way that can co-opt or subsidise those people in positions of authority and
power who want to help, and at the same time bypass, distract, or otherwise
undermine, those opposed to our goal.
Ideally too, we would use market forces. Markets are the most efficient means
yet discovered of allocating society's scarce resources, but many believe that
market forces inevitably conflict with social goals: accentuating extremes of
wealth and poverty, for example, or accelerating the degradation of the
environment. So it is important to remind ourselves that market forces can
serve public, as well as private, goals.
Middle East Peace Bonds
My suggestion is that philanthropists perhaps with governments
and other interested organisations and individuals, collectively raise a large
amount of money, put it into an escrow account, and use these funds to redeem a
new financial instrument: Middle East Peace Bonds. These would be sold by
auction for whatever they would fetch. They would be redeemed for, say, £100 000
each only when all the conditions for peace, as defined by the issuers, had
been satisfied and sustained. Importantly, the bonds would make no assumptions
as to how to bring about greater
peace. Nor would they make any assumptions as to who would hold the bonds or
carry out peace-creating projects. Those decisions would be made by investors
in the bonds. Unlike normal bonds, Middle East Peace Bonds would not bear
interest and their redemption date would be uncertain. Bondholders would gain
most by ensuring that peace is achieved quickly.
Trading the bonds
Middle East Peace Bonds, once floated, must be readily
tradable at any time until redemption. The operation of such a ‘secondary
market’ would be critical to the working of the bond mechanism. Many bond
purchasers would want, or need, to sell their bonds before redemption, which
might be a long time in the future. With tradability, these holders would be able to realise any
capital appreciation experienced by their holdings of Middle East Peace Bonds
whenever they choose to do so. Tradability would make the bonds a more
attractive investment in the first place, and allow us to target an outcome as
remote as peace in the Middle East, that will probably take longer to achieve
than any bondholder’s investment horizon.
As the bonds are traded, they will tend to flow towards
those who can do most to help reduce the violence. In fact, though, an actual
flow of bonds would not be necessary. Large bondholders might simply decide to
subcontract out the required work to many different agents, while they themselves
held the bonds from issue to redemption. The important point is that the bond
mechanism would ensure that the people who allocate the finance had an
incentive to do so efficiently and to reward successful outcomes, rather than
merely to pay people for undertaking activities. At the limit we can conceive
of just one single buyer of all the bonds. If this buyer were determined to
hold on to the bonds until redemption, then the bonds would function as a sort
of performance-related contract, with the backers paying only when the
objective had been achieved. The buyer could contract out most, or all, of the
work required to achieve the objective, with the incentives given by the bonds for
speedy accomplishment cascading down from the bondholder to those subcontracted
to do the work of reducing the violence.
Too large a number of small bondholders could probably do
little to help achieve peace by themselves. If there were many small holders,
it is likely that the value of their bonds would fall until there were
aggregation of holdings by people or institutions large enough to initiate
effective peace-building projects. As with shares in newly privatised companies
the world over, Middle East Peace Bonds would mainly end up in the hands of
large holders, be they individuals or institutions. Between them, these large
holders would probably account for the majority of the bonds. Even these bodies
might not be big enough, on their own, to achieve much without the co-operation
of other bondholders. They might also resist initiating projects until they
were assured that other holders would not be free riders. So there would be a
powerful incentive for all bondholders to co-operate
with each other to help bring about peace in the Middle
East. They would share the same interest in seeing targeted
objectives achieved quickly. So they would share information, trade bonds with
each other and collaborate on conflict-quelling projects. They would also set
up payment systems to ensure that people, bondholders or not, were mobilised to
help build peace. Bondholders would either trade bonds, or make incentive
payments to ensure that any proceeds from higher bond prices, or from
redemption, would be channelled in ways most likely to end the violence. Large
bondholders, in co-operation with each other, would be able to set up such
systems cost-effectively.
Regardless of who actually owned the bonds, aggregation of
holdings, and the co-operation of large bondholders, would ensure that those
who helped build peace were rewarded in ways that maximise the reduction in
violence per unit outlay.
So, in contrast to today’s anaemic, short-term, tried,
tested and failed approaches, a Middle East Peace Bond regime would stimulate
research into finding ever more cost-effective ways of achieving peace. Indeed,
bondholders would be in a better position than governments to undertake a range
of peace-building initiatives. They have the freedom as well as the incentive
to try innovative approaches. They might, for example, finance sports matches
between opposing sides, promote anti-war programmes on TV, set up exchange
schemes for students of the opposing sides. They might even facilitate intermarriage
between members of the opposing communities, or try to influence the financial
supporters of conflict outside the region to redirect their funding into more
positive ways. They could offer the Palestinians and the citizens of
neighbouring Arab countries different forms of aid, including education and
scientific aid, and measures aimed at providing a secular education for all Arab
citizens.
Bondholders could lobby, or work with, the Israeli and Arab governments to, say,
give a higher priority to peace studies in schools, but they could also develop
peace-teaching projects of their own. While immediate peace might not result,
much more could be done to enhance the prospect of peace in the future.
Bondholders could, for instance, make strenuous efforts in Israel and the
neighbouring countries to have some mixed classes of Jewish and Palestinian children
at kindergarten and school. Both groups could be given the chance of spending
time with each other. At the very least, bondholders might think, there should
be opportunities for the younger people from both sides of the conflict to
meet, discuss, argue and form friendships.
Some powerful people in governments, religious institutions or militant organisations
would resent the targeting of such objectives by external agencies in this way.
But, while under the current system they can oppose peace in ways that attract
support, under a Peace Bond regime, they would have openly to declare their opposition to peace itself. It is precisely
this focus on the outcome of peace – rather
than activities or institutions – that would help strengthen the coalition working
to achieve it. We could broaden the definition of peace to include not only
numbers killed or injured, but other quantifiable goals, such as the amount
spent on defence in the region, the results of surveys of people’s fears and
anxieties, or net migration rates. For the bonds to be redeemed, all goals
shall have to be achieved and sustained.
By appealing to people's self-interest, Middle East Peace Bonds are likely to
be more effective than conventional efforts aimed at reducing violence. In channelling
market forces into the achievement of this objective the bonds could bypass or
even co-opt the corrupt or malicious people in government or elsewhere who
stand in the way of peace.
In today's emotional climate decision-making is too often reactive. It is too
easily swayed by those with a propensity for violence or those who benefit from
it, whether financially or emotionally. Governments can evade or deflect
censure on grounds of communal affiliation or patriotism, because the adverse
effects of their policies are difficult to relate to their cause. Middle East Peace
Bonds would focus on an identifiable outcome and channel market efficiencies
into exploring the ways of achieving it. They could be the most effective means
of achieving the peace that the people of the Middle East yearn for and
deserve.
© Ronnie Horesh, September 2012.